Navigation Bar


"Is Switzerland democracy's wave of the future"
Direct Democracy in Switzerland
Foreword by NASDAQ Vice Chairman Alfred R. Berkeley
April, 2002

Important books must either impart vital information or expose an important new idea. Interesting books must tell a good, human story. In Democracy in Switzerland, Gregory Fossedal has done something rare - he's done a bit of all three. The result is a highly readable story, a tale of William Tell defying arrogant lords, and brave mountain men and women fighting off gangs black knights to establish the world's only 1000-year< democracy. #

At the same time, Fossedal tells how one of the world's countries least blessed with physical resources has come to be, arguably, the most successful economy in the world, and how a nation with pervasive religious and linguistic divisions enjoys profound social tranquility - information that is surely important to people around the world, and even in America.

Finally, Democracy in Switzerland raises important issues for the future of democracy itself, much in the way Alexis de Tocqueville's Democracy in America suggested the need for political freedom to a Europe straining under the dead hand of aristocrats and top-down, elite politics. For, as Fossedal notes, the Swiss democracy is very different from any other system in the world. Switzerland's direct democracy - in which the people, by initiative and referendum, wind up voting directly on a large number of policies that affect their lives - is sufficiently different in operation that it might be called, as the former foreign editor of The Economist, Hal Needham, once suggested, a "different system" altogether. Certainly, democracy in Switzerland is very different in some important features than democracy in America, Asia, or the rest of Europe is today. Switzerland thus may function as a kind of laboratory - both because of its purity in applying the democratic idea, and its long history as a functioning cluster of democracies, a history more than four times as long as the next-longest-running democracy ever, the United States. This attribute is a very valuable one, as, in human political affairs, it is impossible to set up scientifically precise experiments and petri-dish control groups. As well, Switzerland's long experience with this type of democracy, and not always under the most favorable material circumstances, enables other countries with Swiss-like diversity to make analogy to some of its individual experiences. "Like policies," as Abraham Lincoln wrote, "imply like results." Indeed it is possible, as Fossedal notes wryly, that even Americans might learn something from the Swiss experience.

In most Western democracies, the people make only a small number of decisions about economic or social policy for themselves. Instead, we hire experts and elect representatives to make many of these decisions for us. Every now and then - two years, four years, or six years - we hold another election to review the last 10,000 or so decisions by those leaders, as a whole, and, in practical terms, vote for one of two alternatives who will handle the next cluster of thousands of decisions.

Switzerland uses some of these devices to, but to a much greater extend than other democracies, the voters make dozens and even hundreds of the particular decisions themselves. As well, the Swiss have a highly devolved system of federalism in which many decisions that would be made by the federal government or large "state" governments in other countries are made by cantons (some fewer than 100,000 in population) or communities (of which the average is about 3,000 persons). And where the Swiss do employ professional politicians, at whatever level of government, both their pay and their power pale against the clout and compensation of a typical state legislator or even city council member in much of the U.S. The federal parliament meets about 12 weeks a year, its members earn perhaps $40,000 in compensation, and they have virtually no full-time staff - not even offices. The Swiss president is the chairman of a seven-member committee that alternates once a year; the supreme court, some four-dozen judges, many of them without a law degree, who have no authority to discard federal laws, even if they deem them unconstitutional. The Swiss constitution, as Fossedal notes, is literally one written by the people - more than half its provisions, as of the late 20th Century, having derived from popular ballot initiatives or referenda voted on directly by the people.

On the other hand, every male from age 20 to age 50, with a very few exceptions, is a member of the Swiss army. And although it is difficult to measure, the typical Swiss adult probably spends several times the hours per week or month in volunteer service to the cantonal, or community government, than does his or her counterpart in Germany, Japan, Britain, or the United States.

Does all this matter? That is to say, does Swiss democracy differ from U.S. and European representative democracies only in trivial ways - as a salad fork differs from a desert fork, or "aqua" from "sea-blue green"?

As Fossedal narrates the story of democracy in Switzerland, one comes to the conclusion that it does differ importantly from what we think of as an undistinguishable "democracy" in Europe and the Americas. There is a different animating spirit to the thing, and that different spirit produces different results.

I've found in my own experience that two systems which appear to be very similar, which in fact may be identical in many particulars, can be very different in fact. For much of my adult life, I've been the president of the NASDAQ stock exchange, a market where small entrepreneurial companies - at least, initially small ones, as Intel, Amgen, and a little company called "Microsoft" were when they listed there - are able to get access to capital. The same market, not incidentally, also permits investors are able to take a stake in some of the most dynamic new firms in the economy at an early date.

On a superficial level, there are few differences between the NASDAQ market and, say, the New York stock exchange. Both deal in billions of dollars of transactions every day, and with hundreds of companies. Both sell shares that may be bought by the great investment firms of the world, the W.P. Stewarts and the Soros Funds, and both sell shares, at least in some measure, to small firms and even individual investors.

Despite all these similarities, however, the NASDAQ is a very different animal than the New York Stock Exchange - we like to think so, and my guess is, even the people at the NYSE think so too, though we might disagree about which of the differences are most important.

The NASDAQ, for example, lists many times the number of new companies, or initial public offerings, as does the over-the-counter market on Wall Street. This has become, in effect, our special role or function. It is also, however, part of our philosophy for how a market can add value for investors and the economy as a whole.

On the New York exchange, it has traditionally been more difficult for small players to get execution of a trade, to buy and sell an odd number of shares, even to get access to the best and most timely information. With the advent of discount brokerages and online trading, this has changed somewhat. But the NYSE is still, compared to the NASDAQ, a market of larger sellers and larger buyers of equity dealing through large brokerages. The NASDAQ, comparatively, is one of finer gradations of access for companies and investors. It is, or as I tell investors, it strives to be, a highly responsive market that puts the investor first.

By analogy, Fossedal reports, the representative democracies are closer in operation and spirit to the highly-brokered, large cap markets of New York and the other great Western financial cities. Swiss democracy, direct democracy, is a kind of NASDAQ market. In both markets, the investor is ultimately sovereign; but in the one, he exercises sovereignty himself, while in the other, his control is far more subtle and indirect, a sovereignty filtered through a large number of intermediary elites and institutions.

We can think of the different types of democracy, for broad comparison, as if they were two different stock markets. In the first stock market, there are dozens of stocks, available for purchase and sale by anyone who wants to trade and can meet extremely limited requirements. The market is open for trading, let us say, approximately once a month - and more than once a week for small trades with a neighbor or friend. Transactions are final, but if you don't like a particular trade you've made, it's usually possible to make the reverse trade, perhaps at a slightly less advantageous price, a few weeks or even days later. In the second market, one can likewise trade stocks. But this can only be done through a brokerage. Furthermore, in this market, there are only two major stocks, with different sub-shares offering various different dividend plans and the like, but still limited to only two companies. Finally, our second market, for many types of selling and buying, is open only once every four years - once every two years for some more limited transactions. All transactions are final, and what is more, the opportunities to trade back, before the These two markets, in very rough terms, represent direct democracy on the one hand, and representative democracy on the other. The difference between them, roughly, is the difference between Swiss democracy and democracy as we know it.

Is one or the other better? Perhaps there is no general answer to this question. Perhaps, for the economy as a whole, both are needed. Some will feel that the small investor always knows best, and therefore, a market which caters to his needs must ultimately prove superior. Others may feel that investment is a job for seasoned professionals only. The one thing I know is true, is that the difference between these two markets is an important one. If there were specimens of each, it would be worth studying their different impacts and tendencies. Democracy in Switzerland starts from this assumption that the differences matter - and proceeds to narrate how and why they do. The situation he is analyzing, the company he is interested in if you will, is what might be called the NASDAQ of democracies. With its highly decentralized system, its easy access for new entrants, and its relentless focus on the citizen "investor," Switzerland functions as a highly efficient political market. It brings ideas to people faster, and with fewer means of choking them off in transit, than perhaps any other political system in the world. If only on material grounds alone - even if we care nothing about treating investors equally as a goal in and of itself -
Switzerland has given ample reason why this very special market bears close study.

Fossedal is a more than capable observer to tell this story - the story of a people and a political economy. His book is part docu-drama, part financial reporting; a mix of think tank statistics and affable vignettes. The author's affection for his object is not hidden, and is, in fact, a necessary part of telling the story of a country: Were there no respect, and even warmth here, such a book could easily become arid and anti-septic, a kind of literary social studies film.

At the same time, Fossedal is an acute and objective observer. He sees Swiss flaws and reports them, albeit with a sympathetic eye that keeps such flaws in perspective. His chapter on Switzerland and the Holocaust - on the heroic Swiss resistance to Nazi aggression, and its well-meaning but ill-conceived (and at times stubborn) oversights on dormant accounts after the war - is well-reported and cogent. One might even call it moving, as he gets at the drama and emotion of an issue that cannot be discussed only in footnotes to 1940s bank balance sheets. Above all, perhaps, Fossedal has an attribute all too rare among the modern journalists and authors: a self-critical faculty that enables him to suspect when his own observations are biased. Quick to observe and illuminate, he has a Tocquevillian caution about pronouncing final judgments, especially ideological ones. Throughout the book, one has the feeling with Fossedal's first interest and passion is actually democracy itself, the notion of how debates are settled politically, rather than any socialist or libertarian or any sort of agenda. In much Western discussion today, a love of "democracy," as Tocqueville observed, is basically "a tactic" for advancing the interests of a group, or the economic program of a party. It is a means, not an end. Fossedal, it seems, cares about democracy itself; political equality and popular sovereignty as an end, not a means. His interest is not any of the specific companies, so much as the science of how a market is best conducted so all companies, and all investors, benefit as much as possible. We may yet find, in our materialist age, that this focus on first things, on making decisions in a fair way, and in disciplining the caprices of the rulers to the wisdom of the people, winds up being the key even to material prosperity itself. In any case, there is a certain refreshing quality about a book which talks about politics as something that matters, something vital - even something healthy and positive. Is democracy, like a capital market, capable of evolution and perfection? The implicit answer of Democracy in Switzerland is, yes, it is. Indeed, if we consider the advances made in information flow, in the rise of consumer and investor sovereignty through the growth of small-cap stock markets and internet technologies, what is more remarkable is the extent to which our political market has remained unchanged. It may be that those very forces which have revolutionized the world economy, will soon lead to demands for a comparable increase in the responsiveness of our institutions of government.

This evolution, as Fossedal notes, may or may not be towards the kind of highly populist, highly decentralized political market sketched by Fossedal in Democracy in Switzerland. It may, furthermore, be highly desirable for other democracies to be more like that of the Swiss - I happen to think so - or it might be highly inappropriate and undesirable. But in this extensive report on the world's most distinctive democracy, he provides a valuable service. He has taken apart that most delicate and complex of organisms, a political regime, and shown us what makes it tick. Fossedal has gone some lengths, one might even say, towards locating the animating principles, the "spirit of the laws," that are operating in Switzerland after centuries of remarkably pure, undiluted democracy. No sooner has democracy triumphed on the world stage, as The Economist noted in 1991, than a great new debate has begun - the debate over what democracy is, and what it should be; over what is a higher stage of democracy, and what is a regression. No sooner do nearly all men and women agree that the people should rule, than we confront the seemingly prior question of what this means, and how it can best be accomplished. Democracy in Switzerland does not settle that debate. The debate is only just beginning. And it will never be finally settled, because, as Fossedal writes, "there is no end of history." But it is a worthy start to the discussion, an acute and< insightful report on a subject that is, as an economist might put it, "on the margin." It is, as well, a compelling drama, a good story by a writer who combines high ideals with a human touch. A great nation deserves a great work which defines, explores, and elaborates its truths and myths. In Democracy in Switzerland, a great nation has received the telling in history and the placement in history it deserves. It should be widely read in America and Europe, and will, hopefully, have a significant influence on man's understanding and practice of democracy itself.

Alfred R. Berkely is Vice Chairman of the NASDAQ stock
market.